From a purely technical point of view, a bureaucracy is capable of attaining the highest degree of efficiency, and is in this sense formally the most rational known means of exercising authority over human beings.

Max Weber, weirdly enough, in the Australian Government “Report of the Review of the Measures of Agency Efficiency“, March 2011

Whether it was efficient or inefficient, I’ll leave it to you to decide, but I think you’ll agree that only death is truly efficient. Life is very inefficient and not cost-effective at all, from a health-care efficiency point of view.

Victoria Sweet, God’s Hotel

Higher education’s in the headlights in Australia this weekend, as the Federal government has announced plans to fund its schools upgrade by applying significant savings measures to universities, university students and their families.

Cunningly, the proposition was announced in a note slipped to the media on a Saturday when, as one television commentator put it this morning, “everyone’s watching the football.” (Which just goes to show that neither government nor media have any idea how higher education workers spend their weekends.)

People have commented on the logic of cutting support to one part of the educational ecosystem in order to fund another, especially in a village economy like ours. And it’s proving a first rate opportunity to watch apparently progressive, socially-aware policy being communicated awkwardly.

I’m an Australian higher education worker and I have three children in three different public schools. I understand conflict of interest, and I also get that this strategy is an important play for a left-facing government taking a very long run up to an election. There are more votes in the education of my children than there are in the wellbeing and fair treatment of my colleagues.

Still, I’m not convinced by a communications strategy based on the message that higher education has been enjoying government largesse to such an extent that this tiny setback shouldn’t disturb us at all. This is patronising. It underestimates the pragmatism, social conviction and resilience of the higher education sector, and obscures the details of the proposal that deserve careful, constructive thought.

Here’s the part that interests me. $900m of savings will come from the application of a two-year Efficiency Dividend to universities. The Efficiency Dividend has been operating in Australian government for over 20 years, and from certain angles it does come across as a standover tactic, particularly when applied to agencies irrespective of size–indifferent to whether or not they can actually tighten their belts further without passing out. It derives from the belief that public sector organisations in general lack incentive to achieve savings because they’re not profit driven, unlike businesses who offer performance-based dividends back to their investors. Public sector organisations, the thinking goes, plough any savings they make from efficiency back into improving the quality of their outputs.

The problem is that we can’t readily measure the Efficiency Dividend this way as it’s almost as hard to measure quality as it is to measure efficiency. How do we account for the transformation of individuals from one state of capability to another as a direct result of their educational participation? Typically we turn to outputs measured quantitatively (numbers of graduates employed, measurable salary benefit of being a graduate etc.), and inputs measured in terms of standards and risk minimisation (numbers of staff employed per student, level of staff qualification, fiscal and operating sustainability). Then we further apply proxies of reported satisfaction to the complexity of experience (student exit surveys), and finally we submit the whole fruit cake of institutional data to the show judge in the hope of ranking well.

And this is why we end up with plan B: efficiency troped as cost cutting. Like Mark Dapin, I grew up in Britain under Thatcherism, and I remember how strongly the case was made for improving public sector efficiency on the basis of accusations and assumptions about what other people would do if left to their own devices. What we got was socially bad policy ineptly disguised in political euphemism. The long-term result was Billy Bragg, and significant harm to the capacity of government, media and citizens in the UK to work together on more or less any topic.

So as we look at the mess Thatcherism made of the efficiency project, maybe this is a moment for those of us who work in Australian universities to try to tackle efficiency doctrine more purposefully, especially where we have the expertise to know that a blunt instrument approach will not produce good results. In fairness to everyone who will have to make this work, we need to generate both evidence and constructive suggestions, so that we can avoid the almost magnetic lure of false economy that Efficiency Dividend planning represents.

In terms of the bit I know, I believe we should treat both online education and casualisation as efficiency bait that we’d be wise to circle around for a while. Online education in particular isn’t in its infancy, but massively open courses are quite new. They’re soup du jour in efficiency circles because they suggest that content developed and delivered entirely on someone else’s dollar could help us lower the cost of teaching our own students. But we haven’t yet figured out how this would shape the way we develop locally relevant curriculum, or maintain capacity in our own sector; we haven’t confronted the long-term risk they represent to Australia in terms of import dependency. I’ve heard a number of people over the last week say that we’ll always have higher education because we’ll always have cinemas; it seems to me that if this is your view, you need to look much more closely at the economics of cinema in Australia.

So at the end of this odd weekend of TV celebrity for Australian higher education, we need not to panic or simply complain. We have been asked to step back in favour of another part of the education system. Done. But that being the case, we now need to speak up in precise and evidence-based ways about the opportunity cost of applying the Efficiency Dividend to something as complex and socially diverse as Australian higher education. The risks are serious, and can’t be addressed indirectly by fixing the separate, upstream problems of our school system.

For weeks, I’ve been reading Victoria Sweet’s account of her 20 years working as a doctor in the last almshouse in San Francisco, in her book God’s Hotel. The Lagunda Honda hospital was repeatedly subjected to efficiency audit during her time there, and repeatedly found to be in breach of the standards applied. But somehow, doctors and nursing staff working together had achieved extraordinary results in terms of patient care, restoring individuals to life who really had no business living. This continued until the application of measures applied by highly paid consultants to reduce staffing and increase compliance, that had the additional impact of increasing dependency on forms and reporting. Laguna Honda’s auditors lacked the experience to judge the value of the procedures they observed, and misread many.

Care diminished, workers were harmed, and patients lost out. But efficiency increased.

8 Responses

  • Thanks for such a considered post that speaks to the contradictions and – how shall I put this? – stupidity of the “efficiency dividend” argument. I’m currently blogging about research culture and talking about education ecosystems – will be linking to your post a couple of times, I think! 🙂

    Reply
  • Thanks, and welcome.

    I’m so pleased to hear about your focus as I’m conscious that this post doesn’t address the problem of efficiency for either research or innovation — and I’m really aware that we need to look at the impact of our own efficiency expectations on the kinds of relationships we’re just beginning to form with our own edtech sector in Australia. These relationships need a chance to spend some inefficient time just getting themselves together. Innovation is really poorly served by efficiency dividend thinking, which is focused on making business as usual more cost effective, so assumes both stability and maturity in a system, not novelty, hesitancy, provisionality or risk, all of which are so important to research and innovation.

    So this is one of the things I feel it’s most important to defend — that not everything we do is ready to have its costs cut, while we’re still working out what it is.

    Reply
  • Couldn’t agree more. The analogy with healthcare is a really good one. Numbers can be really useful for benchmarking effectiveness – it is important to know where you stand in relation to the number of deaths or long term prognosis following a particular surgical procedures, compared to other hospitals, for instance. Similarly, in a university if only 20% of your students find graduate jobs, compared to a national average of 60%, then you might decide you need to work on that area. But good numbers in those areas don’t make you efficient, necessarily. Nor do they say much about the complexity of the humans who were affected by your surgical intervention, or by the courses you offered, although there may be some ways of normalising this, if you have large enough data sets and you’re prepared to simplify a bit.

    But that’s not about efficiency. If we were going to aim for efficiency, a good start would be getting to a point where academics don’t work at weekends, to take the topic of yesterday’s post. I do wonder if that would have an impact on effectiveness as well as morale, or do we just do it because we love the job so much?

    Reply
    • Hello, welcome. I really think your question at the end about the connection between effectiveness and morale is an important one, and Victoria Sweet writes about this beautifully. She describes the practical effect on patient care of staff who had become demotivated, and had no time to think. For me, the correlation between education and health care is the curious question of vocation: people go into these kinds of work because they have values that really align to the values of the institutions they work in. So if those institutions change their apparent values, this productive alignment is thrown out, and then it seems to me that there’s a like cost in terms of efficiency, because the whole system is running just a bit less smoothly.

      I do think academics (especially casual academics) need to be careful of the love trap. Watching academics talk about “the job I love” on Twitter prompted my previous post, about the time I spend working and the time I spend with the people I really do love, heart and soul. So I guess I’m thinking a bit about loving a job that doesn’t actually love you back, and would replace you in a heartbeat, as opposed to trying to be present with the people who love you, and miss you when you’re absent.

      Reply
  1. Fear of death by 1000 cuts | The Banana Lounge  April 15, 2013

    […] Kate Bowles (@KateMfD), who blogs at Music for Deckchairs, has written a great post on this efficiency dividend issue. […]

  2. On memory, profitability, disruption and socialised alternatives | Richard Hall's Space  April 16, 2013

    […] memory: In scoping the policy space inside which Australian Higher Education is being restructured, Kate Bowles argues for recognising the complexity of higher education in all its forms, and for finding spaces […]

  3. And they don’t even know enough to expect better | The Weblog of (a) David Jones  April 16, 2013

    […] to mistakes which need to be fixed. Leading to less than stellar efficiencies (which last weekend took on a much higher profile within Australian higher […]

  4. Myths about research cultures | The Research Whisperer  April 30, 2013

    […] As I was digesting information about the funding cuts a few weeks ago, I read Kate Bowles’ considered piece on the folly of applying an “efficiency dividend” to higher education. […]

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.